Some may complain of a lack of detailed proposals or, worse,
a lack of politically practicable proposals. But, at a time when the decencies
of civilized living are daily beset by the exigencies of rapid material
development, detailed proposals are secondary to what I deem to be the main
task: that of convincing people of the need of radical change in our habitual
ways of looking at economic events. As for political practicability, it is not
too hard to foster a reputation for sound judgment and realism by a conspicuous
display of moderation in moving with the times and a care to suggest nothing
that the public is not just about ready to accept in any case. Such political
sense has its uses, but it has nothing to contribute in any radical
reassessment of social policy. Ideas that seem, at first, to be doomed to political
importance may strike root in the imagination of ordinary men and women,
spreading and growing in strength until ready to emerge in political form. For
what is politically feasible depends, in the last resort, on the active
influences on public opinion.
The External Diseconomies of Built-up Areas
There are technological limits to the economies of size.
Even assuming these economies of size to be large, there are countervailing
diseconomies of size. The larger the city the more time and resources have to
be spent within the city on the movement of people and goods. Even telephone
communication can become wasteful as the numbers in commerce and the
professions increase. Any growth of
building
densities in city centers adds further to the difficulties of traffic that has
passed the point of mutual frustration.
The effects of any
additional population, in adding to the traffic, and ultimately in time spent
commuting, in adding to the noise and grime, and the impact of this increased
pressure on people’s health and disposition are not taken into account by
commerce and industry. Important though they are, they are difficult to
measure. In the absence of pertinent legislation the incentive for expanding
firms to bring them into the cost calculus is virtually non-existent.
The extent of the social
damage inflicted by traffic congestion, even on itself alone, tends to be
underrated by a public which habitually thinks in terms of an average figure
rather than in terms of the appropriate marginal concept.
Of no less topical interest
is the growth of the city’s population. Each person who chooses to live in the
metropolis has no thought of the additional costs he necessarily imposes on
others, and especially over the short period during which it is not possible to
add to the existing accommodation, road space or public transport facilities.
In the more crowded parts of the metropolitan area it requires no more than a
few thousand immigrants to reduce in remarkable degree the standard of comfort
of all the previous inhabitants of the area. If the immigrants into the city
happen to arrive from other parts of the country, or from other parts of the
world enjoying comparable standards, the degree of discomfort suffered by the
existing inhabitants, though incompatible with any optimal situation, will
remain within limits. For such immigration will not continue if living
conditions in such areas fall too far below the standards generally expected.
If, on the other hand,
immigrants come from countries with standards of living, of hygiene and
comfort, well below those prevalent in the host country, the standards of the
neighborhood within which the immigrants elect to settle may have to decline
drastically before the standards themselves begin to act as a disincentive to further
immigration. Indeed, the immigrants may be willing to tolerate worse conditions
than in the homeland since (i) those who pioneer the immigration will be
prepared to endure hardship for a year or two in the hope of bettering their
lot later, and (ii) some are resigned to dwell in squalid conditions for
several years with the aim, initially at least, of amassing a sum of money in
order either to return or to bring over their families. Moreover, there is
always a time-lag, measured perhaps in years, between the worsening of
conditions in immigrant areas of the city and the general appreciation of this
face in the immigrants’ homelands.
External Diseconomies and
Social Conflict
A more menacing source of conflict at this stage in
world history, though people appear reluctant to recognize the fact, is that
arising from continued population expansion and, more recently, mass migration.
In very poor countries, such as
To put the matter bluntly, there
are no longer vast inhabitable areas to be peopled in
Moreover, large-scale
immigration is not only likely to be socially unsettling, in an economy as
close to full employment as that of the United Kingdom and the United States
has been since the war, it is almost sure to have a net inflationary impact on
the economy. A large-scale inflow of relatively unskilled labor therefore acts
as a distributionally regressive force (inasmuch as profits and, to a lesser
extent, wages increase at the expense of fixed income groups including
pensioners). In addition, an increase of population from abroad, like an
increase in the indigenous population, raises the demand for imports (even in
the complete absence of upward pressure on domestic prices) without inducing a
corresponding increase of exports thereby worsening the balance-of-payments position─or
worsening the terms of trade in the longer run.¹
Nonetheless, I am inclined to rate very much
higher than these untoward economic effects the impact of large-scale
immigration on the existing diseconomies of an already too-large-for-comfort
population and the already intractable traffic problem. These diseconomies will
necessarily be aggravated and frequently localized by immigration into this
rather tight little island²
It may
be observed in passing that this conflict between the existing inhabitants of a
region and would-be immigrants is also to be found within the frontiers of a
single country. For instance, according to Professor Raymond Dasmann, the
beauty and natural resources of
From the destruction wrought
by large population movements to that wrought by mass tourism is a short step
and one that opens up a vista of the immeasurable destructive potential of
indiscriminate economic growth. In the last decade alone there has been
something of a holocaust of the scarcest of our earthly resources, natural
beauty. In this instance the conflict of interest is between, on the one hand,
the tourists, tourist agencies, traffic industries and ancillary services, to
say nothing of governments anxious to augment their reserves of foreign
currencies, and all those who care about preserving natural beauty on the
other. There is obviously also a conflict of interest between present and
future generations.
1. It
is sometimes argued in the popular press that this country benefits from
immigrants’ willingness to enter unpopular occupations where services are
maintained without raising costs to the public. This is however, a one-sided
analysis. When account is taken of the domestic opportunities for improved
allocation in the absence of immigration the argument no longer holds. This
topic among others will be discussed by Dr. Needleman and me in a forth-coming
paper on the longer term economic consequences of large-scale immigration.
2. It
is a sad reflection on our times that scientists interested in the “population
explosion” are concerned for the most part with the purely technical problem of
feeding the swelling populations. Schemes range from more high-powered animal
farms to processing grass, and from exploiting the seas to making plastic meat
substitutes.
That already man has broken
all ecological bounds and that, unless one can somehow reverse the trends, the
world’s population will have doubled by the end of the century; that thereafter
we shall be as thick as locusts over many parts of the inhabitable earth—all
this is as nothing to the vision of growthmen who continue to exorcise any
future specter with the word challenge.