DT
:
Please tell us about your early years.
EM
: My father, who was
a textile importer, and mother came from
My father had opened a
textile mill by then in
I realized that if I went
into economics I’d know a lot more about business than my father! So I went to
Manchester University and took my first degree there in economics, then to the
London School of Economics for two years and then to Chicago for two years,
where I took my doctorate, my supervisor being Milton Friedman. I got into the
London School of Economics as assistant lecturer in 1956.
I gradually moved up the ladder to become
professor in 1974, but resigned my chair in l977 to take up a position in a
number of American universities until 1983 when I had to retire—although I felt
sure I could have continued teaching for another 20 years.
DT
:
A belief in
economic growth often goes hand in hand with ‘progress.’ What first made you
doubt these parallel myths?
EM
: I remember
standing on a bridge over a busy road in
In 1959, the editors of the
two premier economic journals in
I was elected to write the
one on welfare economics, which deals with the allocation of scarce resources
so as to advance the general welfare. It turned out to be quite a success and
was translated into many languages, including Japanese. Yet I ended the survey
expressing misgivings about any theoretical progress in the subject having any
guidance to offer in promoting welfare, at least in the West. The more I
thought about the matter, the more I began to suspect that continued economic
growth in the West was, on balance, more 1ikely to diminish than lo enhance the
welfare of society.
During seminars organized to
discuss the issues I raised, my views were not well received. Nearly all my
colleagues virtually pounced on me, occasionally suggesting that I was
romanticizing about some golden age that had never existed, but it was nothing
like that. I thought more and more about it and wrote other articles on the
theme, and finally, in 1965, my book
The Costs of Economic Growth one
publisher after another dismissed it and called me a dreamer, so I pushed it
into a drawer and forgot about it.
In 1966, a young man, Lionel
Needleman, joined the economics staff at LSE and during a conversation I
mentioned my ill—fated book. He said he knew of a publisher who would publish
anything. I sent the MS to him, but even he was lukewarm, and in reply sent two
pages of cynical comments by his reader. I promptly ‘phoned his secretary and
said I would withdraw it unless he accepted it exactly as written. To my
surprise, he agreed.
It turned out to be a
tremendous success, and received ‘rave reviews’ even from academic economists.
That was the beginning of my ‘fame’ or notoriety.
I received invitations to lunch or dine with
a number of well-known editors and other important people, offers to give
public lectures at which I enjoyed red-carpet treatment. In l97l, while in
DT
:
Eminent though
you are, you are in a small minority amongst economists and educated opinion in
general. Why do people go along with the idea of endless economic growth?
EM
: Other economists
were too busy keeping up with the growth of the economic literature or seeking
to advance their prospects—although, later on, about the 1970s—journals and
books on environmental economics began to appear.
Then,
many economists and business leaders were persuaded by a famous article written
by Ronald Coase published in the
Journal of Law and Economics in 1960.
There he argued that, given a proper system of property rights in all
resources, a competitive economy would of itself bring about an ideal
allocation of goods and resources without any intervention of governments, In other
words, we didn’t have to worry any more about the spillover effects of industry
or any economic activity: Just leave it to the market!
Obviously
such a theorem became very popular among
There
was a recent television series on economic growth and happiness. Among others
they also consulted Lord (Richard) Layard, who was one of my graduate students
in the Sixties. He gave reasons why greater material growth may not be expected
to increase happiness—all of which reasons can be found in my
Costs of
Economic Growth—although it is immodest in me to say so.
[
Editor’s
Note: Lord Layard is founder-director of the LSE Centre for Economic
Performance.]
DT
:
Isn’t
cost-benefit analysis a fairly crude tool?
EM
: CBA’s
not crude, but it’s extremely slippery. Perhaps that’s why I was attracted to
it. My book
Cost-Benefit Analysis (1971) was the first book that ever
came out on the subject. I’ve just finished the fifth edition.
You can get pretty far with CBA in the absence of
uncertainty about the future. Uncertainty implies that you don’t even know the
probabilities of the future movements of prices and other variables. It has
become an increasingly popular technique, but the question of the wellbeing of’
individuals, whether they will get greater enjoyment of life or not, doesn’t
come within its ambit.
DT
:
You
have been accused of being anti-science and anti-technology, because you
believe that scientific research is limited in its usefulness and has
unquantifiable implications. Can you clarify your views?
EM
: I’m
neither anti-science nor anti-technology, but I do recognize their limitations.
For example, the computer and the Internet have had all kinds of consequences
which I would rather do without. Terrorists, sex offenders, and paedophiles can
all communicate more easily, and it has been used to penetrate military
secrets. You could possibly even use the internet to shut down whole
industries. I even wish we hadn’t invented the automobile and air travel. Has
technology made us feel better on the whole—has it made us a closer knit
community? It hasn’t worked that way.
I just point these things out; I can’t give any
solutions to the
problems. In fact, I don’t think there is any way of stopping it. The
culmination of all this is that we are on a path of self-destruction. So much
money is poured into research; so many people depend upon it. It has enormous
corrupting power.
DT
:
There seems to
have been a move away from market fundamentalism in recent years. David
Cameron, for instance, now talks about well-being being more important than
GNP. Is this just electioneering or a genuine change of heart?
EM
: I don’t think it
will go very far. Milton Friedman recommends competitive capitalism as the
solution and I can understand that point of view. If you had to choose between
central direction or resources or the market I would always prefer the market
for the reasons he gives—most importantly, the dissemination of power rather
than having it concentrated in one place.
I don’t think there is much
else you can do about economic growth except to be aware of it. The power
wielded today by conglomerates and monopolies is extraordinary. I can’t see how
you can counter that unless you give more power to the state. We’ve got the
Mergers and Monopolies Commission which occasionally acts, but when we are
talking of globalization we are also talking of gigantic trans-planetary
business concerns wielding great social and political power. I don’t think
there is much hope of persuading them to expand more slowly, or to think of the
effects on people’s welfare.
DT
:
Certainly not
when the mainstream political Left has bought into market reductionism as well.
People seem to depend more on the moral influence of non-governmental
organizations than on the government—to hope groups like Greenpeace might make
an impact in time.
EM
: They do indeed
make an impact, if only on the media. But I don’t think it is critical. I am
very pessimistic about the influence they can exert on governments. Think of
all the scientists engaged in research, practical research into innovations
that will change our way of life. There’s no stopping it.
DT
:
Is nobody in
British politics on the right track?
EM
: I can’t think of
anyone, but even if they were on the right track they couldn’t do much about
it. Cameron is not a bad lad. He will probably talk his way to Prime Minister
but he hasn’t got a lot to offer. I don’t think any one has. You’d have to have
supreme power, and not only over
I am a great admirer of
determined environmental groups like Greenpeace, but their occasional successes
can only delay environmental degradation of the planet.
DT
:
What do you
think are the current forces driving immigration policy in the West? Is the
present open-door policy driven solely by economics?
EM
: I can only guess.
What strikes me most is that governments in the West seem to be so ignorant of
basic economics.
Soon after the last World
War, the media kept on about a general shortage of labor in
But the vacancies in
question were spurious: for a rise in pay (and improvement in working
conditions) would have attracted the necessary numbers—which would mean a
distribution of real income to workers in these occupations from the rest of
the working population.
Not only is there no
economic justification for the continuing flow of immigrants to our shores,
but their presence here has created resentment among the indigenous population.
Unavoidably they give rise to social problems, sometimes racial conflicts, that
continue to place a burden on the police and strain our political ingenuity and
our resources.
Yet among the members of the
establishment and among academics, the tendency was to flaunt their enlightened
credentials by welcoming the mass of colored immigrants as a valuable
contribution to our economy and our society. You could say that it was not so
much woeful ignorance as determined ignorance, as purposeful ignorance.
Academics and politicians just didn’t want to know: in any case
I recall that when Needleman
and I were invited to speak at an economics seminar at LSE about our recent
article in one of the economic journals, one containing estimates of the excess
aggregate demand for domestic goods and imports arising from mass immigration,
we came under relentless attack. It felt like being the accused at a
I recently heard Frances
Cairncross, a contributor to the
Economist, speaking on the radio about
the pensioner problem. According to Miss Cairncross, since the ratio of workers
to pensioners was declining, owing to the decline in the indigenous birth
rate, the required ratio could be restored by immigrant workers. Moreover, we
may not have to continue this immigration indefinitely as the immigrants could
be expected to have larger families. I have to admit I almost exploded while
listening to her. Of all the conceivable ways of tackling the pension problem,
this was, far and away, the daftest criminal lunacy.
The obvious and simple way
to maintain standards for pensioners is to have workers save and invest more
from their incomes—though not much more if workers agree to retire later in
life than 65 or so.
DT
:
What are the
chief diseconomies of mass immigration?
EM
: The
main disadvantage is that it acts over time to lower real income. The more capital
to labour the higher living standards are.
There is also a strong
relationship, especially in this country, between total income and total
imports; the more people come in, the more goods we import. Thus mass
immigration acts to turn the terms of trade against us. And this takes the form
of a rise in the costs of imported goods and materials, so reducing average
real income. What is more, if the rise in the costs of goods is significant, it
is almost certain to lead to claims for higher wages and, possibly, a
wage-price spiral.
Of course, life would be easier if all of us resigned
ourselves to the unavoidable fluctuations in the costs of imports—that is,
without making wage claims whenever the costs moved against us. But given what
Daniel Bell called “the revolution of rising expectations,” characteristic of
Western societies today, we can be sure that wage claims will continue over the
foreseeable future whatever the pretexts.
The third element is the
limited supply of land, especially important in a relatively small country like
ours. Over the inter-war period about four million new houses were built in
DT
:
What are the
chief effects of the global population growth we have seen in recent decades?
EM
: If I recall
correctly, in the mid l940s, world population was estimated to be about 2.5
billion. Today, it is between 7 and 8 billion, the greater part in
The Chinese government is
conscious of population growth and is trying to prevent it in its own country.
But there is no attempt to control population growth in
Life on this earth would be
a lot easier and more comfortable if the population were only a fraction of
what it is. An ideal population for
Thinking
of population controls, I’m not anti-contraceptive. But allowing schoolgirls
access to the pill or giving out condoms to schoolchildren can only make them
feel that if they are not having regular sexual activity they are not behaving
normally. However, I am anti-abortion. As a means for reducing population
growth, it is immoral. Once you have created a potential human life, an embryo,
you have a moral responsibility toward it.
DT
:
What can be done
to spread the gospel of sustainable economics?
EM
: I have never
offered a solution. All over the world people are now fixated on economic
growth. But we should be able, in this country, to make modern life less
abrasive for sensitive people. In my
Costs of Economic Growth I put forward
the idea of setting aside large “amenity areas” for those who wanted to opt out
of certain wearisome aspects of modem life—areas over which aircraft would not
be allowed to venture, where there was no motorized traffic (only
electric-powered public transport), no motorized garden implements, no loud
stereophonics, and so on. Such areas would differ in size, location, and
composition of amenities offered. But they would require legislation. Yet
immersed as we are in a seeming struggle to “maintain our competitive edge” and
somehow to “keep our position in the growth league tables,” such opportunities
of creating for ourselves, or at least for some of us, a more leisurely,
quieter way of life—technically quite possible—are dismissed as the stuff of
dreams.
In the meantime, I cannot
escape the feeling that some great catastrophe is drawing nearer. Among the
growing dangers, one must include the massive growth of cities of over 15 or 20
million in
DT
:
Your worldview
encompasses ethical as well ü economical considerations. Do you have any
religious faith?
EM
: I would rather
have a world in which every one believed in God. Religion can be an immense
source of comfort and solace to people. Of course, it cannot be doubted that
religion has lent itself to all sorts of abuses. But then any institution
disposing of enormous power is bound to lend itself to corruption. Yet, at
least among the countries of the West, religion has been fading from our lives.
It is no longer a real force in our lives. Lost innocence cannot be restored.
Once we are aware that over hundreds of millions of years creatures, large and
small, have evolved that survive only by preying on each other, either as
parasites or tearing and clawing others to death to devour them, it is hardly
possible to believe in God. It may be possible to believe in some omnipotent
source of power, but certainly not a caring or benevolent one.
DT
:
What is your
guiding philosophy?
EM : My guiding philosophy is simply to resign myself to the inevitable: To “eat, drink, and be merry,” for tomorrow I will cease to be.